Module 1, Submodule 2
In Progress

1.2 Alternative Distribution Theories: Ricardo, Kaldor, Kaleeki

Module Progress
0% Complete

I. Introduction to Alternative Distribution Theories

Overview of Distribution Theories

Definition and Importance
Distribution theories in economics are frameworks that explain how income and wealth are distributed among different factors of production, such as labor, capital, and land. These theories are crucial for understanding economic inequality, policy-making, and the dynamics of economic growth. They help in analyzing how different economic policies affect the distribution of income and wealth, thereby influencing social and economic stability.

Historical Context

Evolution of Distribution Theories
The study of income distribution has evolved significantly over time. In the early 19th century, classical economists like David Ricardo laid the foundation for distribution theories with his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817). Ricardo’s work focused on the distribution of income between landowners, capitalists, and laborers. In the mid-20th century, Nicholas Kaldor introduced his alternative distribution theory, emphasizing the role of savings and investment in income distribution. Around the same time, Michal Kalecki developed his theory, which incorporated elements of monopoly power and class struggle into the analysis of income distribution.

Key Economists

Contributions of Ricardo, Kaldor, and Kalecki

David Ricardo
Nicholas Kaldor
Michal Kalecki
  • David Ricardo: Ricardo’s theory of distribution is centered on the labor theory of value, which posits that the value of a good is determined by the amount of labor required to produce it. He introduced the concept of economic rent, which is the income earned by landowners due to the scarcity of land. Ricardo’s theory also includes the subsistence wage theory, suggesting that wages tend to gravitate towards a subsistence level, and the profit theory, which highlights the role of capital accumulation in determining profits.
  • Nicholas Kaldor: Kaldor’s distribution theory, presented in his seminal paper “Alternative Theories of Distribution” (1955), challenges the classical view by focusing on the relationship between savings, investment, and income distribution. He argued that the distribution of income between wages and profits is determined by the propensity to save out of profits and wages. Kaldor introduced the concept of marginal productivity theory, which explains how the distribution of income is influenced by the marginal productivity of labor and capital.
  • Michal Kalecki: Kalecki’s theory of distribution incorporates elements of monopoly power and class struggle. He argued that the degree of monopoly, which refers to the market power of firms, plays a crucial role in determining the distribution of income. Kalecki also emphasized the importance of mark-up pricing, where firms set prices above marginal costs to earn profits. His theory highlights the conflict between labor and capital, with income distribution being influenced by the bargaining power of workers and capitalists.

Objectives

Analyzing, Comparing, and Criticizing Different Theories
The primary objective of studying alternative distribution theories is to analyze, compare, and criticize the contributions of Ricardo, Kaldor, and Kalecki. This involves:

  • Analyzing: Understanding the fundamental principles and assumptions of each theory, and how they explain the distribution of income and wealth.
  • Comparing: Identifying the similarities and differences between the theories, such as their views on the role of labor, capital, and land in income distribution.
  • Criticizing: Evaluating the strengths and weaknesses of each theory, considering their empirical validity, relevance in contemporary economic contexts, and policy implications.

II. Ricardo’s Distribution Theory

Basic principles

Labor theory of value
David Ricardo’s labor theory of value posits that the value of a commodity is determined by the amount of labor required to produce it. This theory, elaborated in his book On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817), suggests that goods are exchanged based on the labor time embodied in them. Ricardo, along with Adam Smith and Karl Marx, argued that labor is the source of all value in an economy. For example, if it takes 20 hours to produce a pair of shoes and 10 hours to produce a hat, the shoes would be valued twice as much as the hat.

Subsistence wage theory
Ricardo’s subsistence wage theory, also known as the iron law of wages, asserts that wages naturally tend to gravitate towards a subsistence level. This means that workers’ wages will be just enough to sustain their lives and enable them to work. If wages rise above this level, the population would increase, leading to a surplus of labor and a subsequent drop in wages back to the subsistence level. Conversely, if wages fall below subsistence, the population would decrease, causing wages to rise again.

Rent theory

Differential and absolute rent
Ricardo’s rent theory distinguishes between differential rent and absolute rent.

  • Differential rent: This arises due to differences in the fertility and productivity of land. Ricardo identified two types:
    • Differential Rent I: Extra profit is transformed into rent when equal amounts of capital are invested on lands of unequal productivity.
    • Differential Rent II: Differences in profitability result from unequal amounts of capital being invested successively on the same type of land.
  • Absolute rent: This type of rent is extracted by landowners due to their monopoly over land. It arises because agricultural production has a lower organic composition of capital compared to industry, meaning that the value of agricultural output is higher than its production cost.

Profit theory

Role of capital accumulation
Ricardo’s profit theory emphasizes the importance of capital accumulation in determining profits. He argued that profits are what remain after wages and rents have been paid from the gross revenue. Capitalists invest in both fixed capital (like machinery) and working capital (like wages). According to Ricardo, the rate of profit is influenced by the productivity of labor and the cost of production. He also noted that as capital accumulates, the rate of profit tends to fall due to the diminishing returns on investment in agriculture.

The figure illustrates the distribution of income in Ricardo’s model. It shows the relationship between population and income components: total output (Y), total subsistence wage (S), and output minus rent (Y-R). As population increases from 0 to P1​, total output rises to point R. The subsistence wage increases from S0​ to 𝑆2, while the surplus (output minus rent) is represented by the distance between 𝑌 and 𝑅. The model highlights how income is distributed among wages, rent, and surplus as population changes.

III. Kaldor’s Distribution Theory

Basic principles

Marginal productivity theory
Nicholas Kaldor’s marginal productivity theory posits that the distribution of income between wages and profits is determined by the marginal productivity of labor and capital. This theory suggests that each factor of production is paid according to its contribution to the production process. Kaldor emphasized that the share of income going to labor and capital depends on their respective marginal products. For example, if the marginal product of labor increases due to higher productivity, wages would rise accordingly.

Role of capital and labor
Kaldor highlighted the interdependence between capital and labor in determining income distribution. He argued that the distribution of income is influenced by the relative shares of capital and labor in the production process. In his view, the accumulation of capital leads to higher productivity, which in turn affects the distribution of income. Kaldor’s approach integrates the dynamics of savings and investment, showing how these factors impact the overall economic growth and income distribution.

Savings and investment

Impact on income distribution
Kaldor’s theory underscores the crucial role of savings and investment in shaping income distribution. He argued that the propensity to save differs between capitalists and workers, with capitalists typically saving a larger proportion of their income. This differential saving behavior influences the distribution of income, as higher savings lead to increased investment and economic growth. Kaldor’s model suggests that shifts in income distribution are essential to achieving a higher saving-income ratio, which is necessary for sustained economic growth.

Technical progress
Influence on distribution
Kaldor introduced the concept of the technical progress function, which replaces the traditional production function. According to Kaldor, the rate of increase in output per worker is an increasing function of the rate of investment. This means that technical progress, driven by investment, plays a pivotal role in determining the distribution of income. Kaldor argued that technical progress acts as the main engine of growth, influencing productivity and, consequently, the distribution of income. For instance, advancements in technology can lead to higher productivity, thereby increasing the share of income going to labor.

The figure illustrates Kaldor’s Distribution Theory, showing the relationship between the share of income (S/Y) and the price level (P/Y) across different income levels (Y). The lines S/Y(Y1), S/Y(Y2), and S/Y(Y3) represent varying income levels intersecting at points E0, E1, and E2. This demonstrates how income distribution shifts with changes in economic activity, indicating that higher income levels lead to different income shares and price levels.

IV. Kalecki’s Distribution Theory

Basic principles

Degree of monopoly
Michal Kalecki’s degree of monopoly theory introduces a unique approach to understanding income distribution. This theory suggests that the degree of monopoly power held by firms determines their ability to set prices above marginal costs. Kalecki argued that firms with higher monopoly power can charge higher mark-ups, leading to greater profits. This concept is crucial for analyzing how market structures influence income distribution. For example, in industries with few competitors, firms can exercise significant monopoly power, resulting in higher mark-ups and profits.

Mark-up pricing
Kalecki’s mark-up pricing theory explains how firms set prices by adding a mark-up to their prime costs, which include wages and raw materials. This mark-up covers overheads and ensures profitability. Kalecki emphasized that the size of the mark-up depends on the degree of monopoly power. Firms with greater market power can impose higher mark-ups, leading to higher prices and profits. This pricing strategy is prevalent in various industries, including manufacturing and services, where firms seek to maximize their returns by leveraging their market position.

Role of class struggle

Labor vs. capital
Kalecki’s theory incorporates the concept of class struggle between labor and capital. He argued that income distribution is influenced by the bargaining power of workers and capitalists. In this framework, wages and profits are determined by the relative strength of labor unions and employers. For instance, strong labor unions can negotiate higher wages, reducing the share of income going to capitalists. Conversely, weak labor unions result in lower wages and higher profits for capitalists. This dynamic reflects the ongoing conflict between labor and capital over the distribution of economic resources.

Savings and investment

Impact on income distribution
Kalecki’s theory also examines the role of savings and investment in income distribution. He argued that capitalists save a larger proportion of their income compared to workers. This higher savings rate leads to increased investment, which in turn affects income distribution. Kalecki suggested that the distribution of income between wages and profits is influenced by the level of investment in the economy. Higher investment levels can lead to greater economic growth, but they also reinforce the income disparity between capitalists and workers.

The figure illustrates Kalecki’s Distribution Theory, depicting the dynamic relationship between demand (D) and income (Y). The curve 𝐷(𝑡)=Φ[𝑠𝑌(𝑡),𝐾(1)] represents the demand function influenced by income and capital. The line 𝑌(𝑡)=𝑓(𝐷(𝑡−1)) shows income as a function of past demand. The equilibrium point 𝐸 is where both curves intersect, indicating stable income and demand levels (𝑌∗ and 𝐷∗). The points 𝑌1 and 𝑌2 show different income levels leading to varying demand levels (𝐷1 and 𝐷2). This model highlights the feedback loop between income and demand in Kalecki’s theory

V. Comparative Analysis of Distribution Theories

Theoretical foundations

Assumptions and implications

  • Ricardo: David Ricardo’s distribution theory is based on the labor theory of value, which assumes that the value of goods is determined by the labor required for their production. This theory implies that income distribution is influenced by the productivity of labor and the availability of land. Ricardo’s assumptions include the subsistence wage theory, which suggests that wages tend to stabilize at a subsistence level, and the concept of economic rent, which arises from the scarcity of land.
  • Kaldor: Nicholas Kaldor’s distribution theory relies on the marginal productivity theory, which posits that income distribution is determined by the marginal productivity of labor and capital. Kaldor’s assumptions include the differential saving behavior of capitalists and workers, with capitalists saving a larger proportion of their income. This theory implies that income distribution is influenced by the propensity to save and invest, as well as the rate of technical progress.
  • Kalecki: Michal Kalecki’s distribution theory is centered on the degree of monopoly, which suggests that firms with higher monopoly power can set prices above marginal costs, leading to greater profits. Kalecki’s assumptions include the role of class struggle between labor and capital, with income distribution being influenced by the bargaining power of workers and capitalists. This theory implies that market structures and the degree of monopoly power play a crucial role in determining income distribution.

Empirical evidence

Real-world applications and case studies

  • Ricardo: Empirical evidence for Ricardo’s theory can be observed in historical and contemporary agricultural economies, where land scarcity leads to economic rent. For example, in India, the Green Revolution increased agricultural productivity, but the benefits were unevenly distributed, leading to higher rents for landowners.
  • Kaldor: Kaldor’s theory finds empirical support in the analysis of savings and investment patterns in developed economies. For instance, in post-independence India, the government’s focus on industrialization and investment in infrastructure led to significant economic growth and changes in income distribution.
  • Kalecki: Kalecki’s theory is supported by empirical studies on market structures and monopoly power. In India, the dominance of large conglomerates in sectors like telecommunications and pharmaceuticals illustrates how monopoly power can influence pricing and income distribution.

Policy implications

Recommendations for economic policy

  • Ricardo: Ricardo’s theory suggests that policies should focus on improving labor productivity and managing land resources effectively. Land reforms and investments in agricultural technology can help address issues related to economic rent and income distribution.
  • Kaldor: Kaldor’s theory implies that policies should encourage savings and investment, particularly in sectors that drive technical progress. Tax incentives for investment, support for research and development, and measures to increase the savings rate can help achieve a more equitable income distribution.
  • Kalecki: Kalecki’s theory highlights the importance of regulating monopoly power and ensuring fair labor practices. Policies aimed at promoting competition, strengthening labor unions, and implementing progressive taxation can help mitigate the effects of monopoly power on income distribution.

Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Ricardo vs. Kaldor vs. Kalecki

AspectRicardoKaldorKalecki
Value DeterminationLabor theory of valueMarginal productivity theoryDegree of monopoly
Wage TheorySubsistence wage theorySavings and investment influenceClass struggle
Rent TheoryDifferential and absolute rentNot a primary focusNot a primary focus
Profit TheoryRole of capital accumulationInvestment and savings impactMark-up pricing
CriticismsSimplistic assumptions, limited modern relevanceEmpirical challenges, policy implicationsComplexity of monopoly power and class dynamics
Modern RelevanceFoundational but outdated in some aspectsInfluential in income distribution policiesRelevant in analyzing market power and inequality

Strengths

  • Ricardo: Provides a foundational understanding of income distribution based on labor and land productivity; useful for analyzing agricultural economies.
  • Kaldor: Offers insights into the role of savings, investment, and technical progress in income distribution; applicable to industrialized economies.
  • Kalecki: Highlights the impact of monopoly power and class struggle on income distribution; relevant for understanding modern market structures.

Weaknesses

  • Ricardo: Assumes labor as the sole source of value, which is simplistic; does not account for modern economic complexities.
  • Kaldor: Focuses on functional distribution rather than personal distribution; assumptions about saving shares may not hold in all contexts.
  • Kalecki: Overemphasizes the degree of monopoly; does not fully address the role of government policies and international trade.

By examining the theoretical foundations, empirical evidence, and policy implications of Ricardo’s, Kaldor’s, and Kalecki’s distribution theories, one can gain a comprehensive understanding of the factors influencing income distribution and the potential strategies for achieving economic equity.

VI. Criticisms and Modern Relevance

Criticisms of Ricardo

Relevance in contemporary economics

  • Labor theory of value: Critics argue that Ricardo’s labor theory of value is overly simplistic and does not account for the complexities of modern economies. The theory assumes that labor is the sole source of value, ignoring other factors such as technology and capital.
  • Subsistence wage theory: Ricardo’s subsistence wage theory is criticized for not considering the variations in living standards and wage negotiations in contemporary economies. The theory assumes that wages naturally gravitate towards a subsistence level, which is not always the case in modern labor markets.
  • Economic rent: While Ricardo’s concept of economic rent is foundational, it does not fully explain the complexities of modern real estate markets and the role of government policies in land use and taxation.

Criticisms of Kaldor

Relevance in contemporary economics

  • Marginal productivity theory: Kaldor’s marginal productivity theory has faced empirical challenges, particularly in explaining income distribution in economies with high levels of inequality. Critics argue that the theory does not adequately address the role of power dynamics and institutional factors in income distribution.
  • Savings and investment: Kaldor’s assumption of invariable shares of income saved by capitalists and workers is considered too rigid. Empirical evidence shows that these shares tend to change over time, influenced by various economic and social factors.
  • Technical progress: While Kaldor’s emphasis on technical progress is significant, his model does not fully account for the impact of technological advancements on employment and wage disparities in contemporary economies.

Criticisms of Kalecki

Relevance in contemporary economics

  • Degree of monopoly: Kalecki’s focus on the degree of monopoly is criticized for oversimplifying the complexities of modern market structures. Critics argue that the theory does not fully address the role of government policies, international trade, and technological changes in shaping income distribution.
  • Class struggle: Kalecki’s emphasis on class struggle between labor and capital is seen as too deterministic by some economists. The theory does not account for the nuances of labor market dynamics and the impact of globalization on labor relations.
  • Savings and investment: Kalecki’s model does not fully explain the role of financial markets and global capital flows in influencing savings and investment patterns in contemporary economies.

Modern adaptations

How theories have evolved over time

  • Ricardo: Modern adaptations of Ricardo’s theories have incorporated elements of neoclassical economics, focusing on the role of technology and capital in value determination. The concept of economic rent has been expanded to include various forms of rent-seeking behavior in different sectors.
  • Kaldor: Kaldor’s theories have been integrated into post-Keynesian economics, emphasizing the role of demand-led growth and the importance of government intervention in managing economic cycles. His ideas on savings and investment have influenced modern growth models that consider the impact of financial markets and global capital flows.
  • Kalecki: Kalecki’s theories have been adapted to analyze the impact of monopoly power and income inequality in contemporary economies. His ideas on class struggle have been expanded to include the effects of globalization and technological changes on labor markets.

Future directions

Potential areas for further research

  • Ricardo: Future research could explore the integration of Ricardo’s theories with modern behavioral economics, examining how psychological factors influence labor productivity and wage determination. Additionally, studies could investigate the role of digital technologies in creating new forms of economic rent.
  • Kaldor: Further research could focus on the implications of Kaldor’s theories for understanding the impact of climate change on economic growth and income distribution. Researchers could also explore the role of digital currencies and blockchain technology in shaping savings and investment patterns.
  • Kalecki: Future studies could examine the relevance of Kalecki’s theories in the context of the gig economy and the rise of platform-based labor markets. Additionally, research could investigate the impact of artificial intelligence and automation on the degree of monopoly and income distribution.

VII. Synthesis and Conclusion

Synthesis of key findings

Summary of main points

  • Ricardo’s Distribution Theory: David Ricardo’s theory focuses on the labor theory of valuesubsistence wage theory, and economic rent. Ricardo posits that the value of goods is determined by the labor required for their production. His subsistence wage theory suggests that wages tend to stabilize at a subsistence level, while economic rent arises from the scarcity of land.
  • Kaldor’s Distribution Theory: Nicholas Kaldor’s theory is based on the marginal productivity theory, emphasizing the role of savings and investment in income distribution. Kaldor argues that income distribution is determined by the marginal productivity of labor and capital, with differential saving behavior influencing the overall economic growth and income distribution.
  • Kalecki’s Distribution Theory: Michal Kalecki’s theory centers on the degree of monopoly and mark-up pricing. Kalecki suggests that firms with higher monopoly power can set prices above marginal costs, leading to greater profits. His theory also incorporates the concept of class struggle between labor and capital, with income distribution influenced by the bargaining power of workers and capitalists.

Implications for advanced microeconomics

How theories inform current understanding

  • Ricardo: Ricardo’s theories provide foundational insights into the relationship between labor, land, and capital in determining income distribution. His concepts of economic rent and subsistence wages remain relevant for analyzing agricultural economies and land use policies.
  • Kaldor: Kaldor’s emphasis on savings, investment, and technical progress has influenced modern growth models and post-Keynesian economics. His theories highlight the importance of demand-led growth and the role of government intervention in managing economic cycles.
  • Kalecki: Kalecki’s focus on monopoly power and class struggle offers valuable perspectives on income inequality and market structures. His theories are particularly relevant for understanding the impact of globalization, technological changes, and labor market dynamics on income distribution.

Final thoughts

Overall assessment and future outlook

  • Ricardo: Ricardo’s theories, while foundational, have limitations in their applicability to modern economies. Future research could explore the integration of behavioral economics and digital technologies to provide a more comprehensive understanding of income distribution.
  • Kaldor: Kaldor’s theories remain influential in contemporary economic policy discussions. Further research could examine the implications of climate change, digital currencies, and blockchain technology on savings, investment, and income distribution.
  • Kalecki: Kalecki’s theories continue to be relevant for analyzing market power and income inequality. Future studies could investigate the impact of the gig economy, artificial intelligence, and automation on the degree of monopoly and income distribution.

By synthesizing the key findings, implications for advanced microeconomics, and overall assessment of Ricardo’s, Kaldor’s, and Kalecki’s distribution theories, one can gain a comprehensive understanding of the factors influencing income distribution and the potential directions for future economic research.

  1. Critically analyze the role of capital accumulation in Ricardo’s distribution theory and its relevance in contemporary economic contexts. (250 words)
  2. Evaluate Kaldor’s marginal productivity theory in the context of modern economic policies and its impact on income distribution. (250 words)
  3. Compare and contrast the influence of class struggle on income distribution in Kalecki’s theory with that in Ricardo’s and Kaldor’s theories. (250 words)

The Tale of Three Kingdoms: Ricardo, Kaldor, and Kalecki

In a distant world, three kingdoms existed, each ruled by a philosopher-economist who sought to guide their land toward prosperity through unique ideas on how wealth should be distributed among their people. These philosophers—Ricardo, Kaldor, and Kalecki—believed that understanding the flow of wealth was the key to the future of their kingdoms, yet each had a vastly different view on how that flow worked.


Kingdom of Ricardo: The Landlords’ Fortune

David Ricardo was a wise and calculating ruler, obsessed with one simple yet powerful idea—land. In his kingdom, land was the most valuable resource, and Ricardo believed that those who owned land would always have the upper hand in the economy. As crops grew and cities expanded, the landlords grew wealthier, receiving rent from their tenants.

Ricardo noticed that as land became more scarce, rents would rise, and this would lead to what he called “differential rent.” The wealth of the landowners was not earned by their own labor but simply because they owned something others needed. He theorized that income distribution in his kingdom would always favor landlords over workers and capitalists because, as land values increased, more wealth would flow toward the top.

But this created tension in his kingdom. The workers, toiling in the fields and factories, received little for their labor, while the landlords lived in luxury. Ricardo’s theory was simple: as long as land remained scarce, its owners would command more and more wealth, creating a natural imbalance between the landowners, the capitalists, and the workers.

Lesson: In Ricardo’s world, wealth distribution is driven by who controls scarce resources—and in the 19th century, land was the king of resources.


Kingdom of Kaldor: The Balance of Classes

Kaldor, a more dynamic and innovative ruler, believed that his kingdom’s wealth didn’t just depend on scarce land but on the interaction between different classes: capitalists, workers, and the state. He theorized that economic prosperity depended on keeping a delicate balance between them.

Unlike Ricardo, Kaldor saw investment by capitalists as crucial. In his kingdom, the capitalists were not villains but essential players who fueled growth through investments in factories, technology, and infrastructure. They saved more of their income, which meant they could invest and grow the economy. However, this wasn’t a one-way street—workers also mattered. For Kaldor, wages and consumption were key drivers of demand, and the economy needed this spending to keep the wheels turning.

Kaldor proposed a dual distribution theory—profits go to the capitalists to reinvest, while wages go to the workers to spend. The challenge in his kingdom was to strike a balance. If too much wealth went to the capitalists, there would be less demand in the economy because workers couldn’t afford to buy goods. But if too much went to the workers, there wouldn’t be enough investment to fuel future growth. His theory highlighted the importance of maintaining a balanced income distribution to keep the economy stable and growing.

Lesson: Kaldor’s kingdom shows that economic growth and income distribution are interdependent. Capitalists invest, but workers consume, and both are essential for prosperity.


Kingdom of Kalecki: Power and Control

Michał Kalecki ruled his kingdom with a more revolutionary outlook. He believed that economic distribution wasn’t just about land or balance but about power dynamics. His theory drew attention to how those who controlled capital and employment wielded immense power over workers.

Kalecki’s kingdom was more volatile. In his view, capitalists weren’t just providers of investment but also gatekeepers of employment. If workers demanded too high wages or if the economy looked unstable, capitalists could easily withhold investments, leading to unemployment and economic downturns. This gave capitalists disproportionate power over workers and the state. However, Kalecki also noticed something interesting: capitalists often resisted full employment because it gave bargaining power to workers. If everyone had a job, wages would rise, and profits would shrink.

Kalecki’s theory became a tale of class struggle, where income distribution depended on who had more bargaining power—the workers or the capitalists. In times of high employment, workers had the upper hand. In times of economic crisis, the capitalists regained control by slowing investments and creating unemployment.

Lesson: Kalecki’s theory shows that wealth distribution is deeply linked to power structures and that capitalists can manipulate the economy to maintain control over labor.


The Moral of the Story

The three kingdoms tell us that wealth distribution isn’t a straightforward process but depends on who controls key resources, how different classes interact, and who holds the power in society. Ricardo’s theory teaches us that scarcity (of land or other resources) benefits the owners of that resource. Kaldor’s theory emphasizes the need for balance between capital and labor to keep the economy moving. Kalecki, on the other hand, reminds us that the economy is a battleground for power, and income distribution reflects who holds that power at any given time.

These competing visions still resonate today. Whether it’s the rising value of assets (like land or housing), the need for investment-driven growth, or the fight for workers’ rights and full employment, the theories of Ricardo, Kaldor, and Kalecki offer crucial insights into the ever-evolving debate on how societies should distribute wealth.

Responses

X
Home Courses Plans Account